College Pricing. Ben Johnson. April 30, Abstract. Colleges in the United States price discriminate based on student characteristics

Similar documents
College Pricing and Income Inequality

College Pricing and Income Inequality

TRENDS IN. College Pricing

About the College Board. College Board Advocacy & Policy Center

Trends in Student Aid and Trends in College Pricing

Trends in Higher Education Series. Trends in College Pricing 2016

Trends in College Pricing

Music Chapel House Rules and Policies hapelle Musicale Reine Elisabeth, fondation d'utilité publique

November 6, Re: Higher Education Provisions in H.R. 1, the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act. Dear Chairman Brady and Ranking Member Neal:

Availability of Grants Largely Offset Tuition Increases for Low-Income Students, U.S. Report Says

Economics 201 Principles of Microeconomics Fall 2010 MWF 10:00 10:50am 160 Bryan Building

A New Compact for Higher Education in Virginia

Financial aid: Degree-seeking undergraduates, FY15-16 CU-Boulder Office of Data Analytics, Institutional Research March 2017

Alex Robinson Financial Aid

Draft Budget : Higher Education

Modern Trends in Higher Education Funding. Tilea Doina Maria a, Vasile Bleotu b

James H. Williams, Ed.D. CICE, Hiroshima University George Washington University August 2, 2012

Data Glossary. Summa Cum Laude: the top 2% of each college's distribution of cumulative GPAs for the graduating cohort. Academic Honors (Latin Honors)

Admitting Students to Selective Education Programs: Merit, Profiling, and Affirmative Action

AN EXAMPLE OF THE GOMORY CUTTING PLANE ALGORITHM. max z = 3x 1 + 4x 2. 3x 1 x x x x N 2

Michigan and Ohio K-12 Educational Financing Systems: Equality and Efficiency. Michael Conlin Michigan State University

OFFICE OF ENROLLMENT MANAGEMENT. Annual Report

Financing of Higher Education in Latin America Lessons from Chile, Brazil, and Mexico

Math 1313 Section 2.1 Example 2: Given the following Linear Program, Determine the vertices of the feasible set. Subject to:

ABILITY SORTING AND THE IMPORTANCE OF COLLEGE QUALITY TO STUDENT ACHIEVEMENT: EVIDENCE FROM COMMUNITY COLLEGES

Firms and Markets Saturdays Summer I 2014

DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE AND ECONOMICS

Essential Guides Fees and Funding. All you need to know about student finance.

Peer Influence on Academic Achievement: Mean, Variance, and Network Effects under School Choice

Suggested Citation: Institute for Research on Higher Education. (2016). College Affordability Diagnosis: Maine. Philadelphia, PA: Institute for

A comparative study on cost-sharing in higher education Using the case study approach to contribute to evidence-based policy

Paying for. Cosmetology School S C H O O L B E AU T Y. Financing your new life. beautyschoolnetwork.com pg 1

FORT HAYS STATE UNIVERSITY AT DODGE CITY

Quantifying the Supply Response of Private Schools to Public Policies

Enrollment Management has become an important leadership. function on many college and university campuses. It is also.

Options for Tuition Rates for 2016/17 Please select one from the following options, sign and return to the CFO

TUESDAYS/THURSDAYS, NOV. 11, 2014-FEB. 12, 2015 x COURSE NUMBER 6520 (1)

Breneman, Lapovsky, and Meyers describe how in recent years institutional financial aid has

Differential Tuition Budget Proposal FY

CS Machine Learning

What You Need to Know About Financial Aid

On-the-Fly Customization of Automated Essay Scoring

Lahore University of Management Sciences. FINN 321 Econometrics Fall Semester 2017

Trends in Tuition at Idaho s Public Colleges and Universities: Critical Context for the State s Education Goals

Descriptive Summary of Beginning Postsecondary Students Two Years After Entry

EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT

In 2010, the Teach Plus-Indianapolis Teaching Policy Fellows, a cohort of early career educators teaching

When!Identifying!Contributors!is!Costly:!An! Experiment!on!Public!Goods!

Higher Education. Pennsylvania State System of Higher Education. November 3, 2017

An Introduction to School Finance in Texas

The Relationship Between Tuition and Enrollment in WELS Lutheran Elementary Schools. Jason T. Gibson. Thesis

Reinforcement Learning by Comparing Immediate Reward

NATIONAL CENTER FOR EDUCATION STATISTICS RESPONSE TO RECOMMENDATIONS OF THE NATIONAL ASSESSMENT GOVERNING BOARD AD HOC COMMITTEE ON.

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE UNIVERSITY OF EXETER

Cooperative Game Theoretic Models for Decision-Making in Contexts of Library Cooperation 1

Lecture 1: Machine Learning Basics

Higher education is becoming a major driver of economic competitiveness

Chris George Dean of Admissions and Financial Aid St. Olaf College

By Laurence Capron and Will Mitchell, Boston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press, 2012.

NATIONAL CENTER FOR EDUCATION STATISTICS

Student Transportation

How Living Costs Undermine Net Price As An Affordability Metric

WIC Contract Spillover Effects

THE COLLEGE OF WILLIAM AND MARY IN VIRGINIA INTERCOLLEGIATE ATHLETICS PROGRAMS FOR THE YEAR ENDED JUNE 30, 2005

Marketing Management MBA 706 Mondays 2:00-4:50

WIC Contract Spillover Effects

Integrated Pell Grant Expansion and Bachelor s Completion Pay for Performance: A Cost-Effectiveness Analysis. Harrison G. Holcomb William T.

Purdue Data Summit Communication of Big Data Analytics. New SAT Predictive Validity Case Study

CHAPTER 4: REIMBURSEMENT STRATEGIES 24

Volunteer State Community College Strategic Plan,

UCLA Affordability. Ronald W. Johnson Director, Financial Aid Office. May 30, 2012

The Good Judgment Project: A large scale test of different methods of combining expert predictions

Is there a Causal Effect of High School Math on Labor Market Outcomes?

WASHINGTON COLLEGE SAVINGS

Business 712 Managerial Negotiations Fall 2011 Course Outline. Human Resources and Management Area DeGroote School of Business McMaster University

GRADUATE STUDENTS Academic Year

Federal Update. Angela Smith, Training Officer U.S. Dept. of ED, Federal Student Aid WHITE HOUSE STUDENT LOAN INITIATIVES

Functional Skills Mathematics Level 2 assessment

An Empirical Analysis of the Effects of Mexican American Studies Participation on Student Achievement within Tucson Unified School District

A Diverse Student Body

Value of Athletics in Higher Education March Prepared by Edward J. Ray, President Oregon State University

Competition in Information Technology: an Informal Learning

Estimating the Cost of Meeting Student Performance Standards in the St. Louis Public Schools

Mathematics Program Assessment Plan

University of Arizona

Going Broke by Degree: A Review Essay

Overview of Access and Affordability at UC Davis

Series IV - Financial Management and Marketing Fiscal Year

have professional experience before graduating... The University of Texas at Austin Budget difficulties

DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS. GRADUATE HANDBOOK And PROGRAM POLICY STATEMENT

Paying for College. Marla Lewis Office of Student Financial Aid

AGS THE GREAT REVIEW GAME FOR PRE-ALGEBRA (CD) CORRELATED TO CALIFORNIA CONTENT STANDARDS

NDPC-SD Data Probes Worksheet

Financing Education In Minnesota

Social and Economic Inequality in the Educational Career: Do the Effects of Social Background Characteristics Decline?

How Do Colleges Respond to Accountability Pressures? Examining the Relationship between Cohort Default Rates and College Pricing

Healthier US School Challenge : Smarter Lunchrooms

Understanding University Funding

TheCenter. The Myth of Number One: Indicators of Research University. Performance. The Top American Research Universities.

Learning Disability Functional Capacity Evaluation. Dear Doctor,

Transcription:

College Pricing Ben Johnson April 30, 2012 Abstract Colleges in the United States price discriminate based on student characteristics such as ability and income. This paper develops a model of college pricing in which colleges maximize their prestige. Several policy experiments are considered in which the college loses the ability to price discriminate at all or to price discriminate with respect to income. Part I Introduction This paper investigates the pricing decisions of colleges. The college pricing decision is different from other pricing decisions because most students do not pay the full tuition price. Colleges price discriminate, attempting to figure out how much each particular student would be willing to pay, and charging that rate. College financial aid offices meet the difference between the full tuition rate and what the student is deemed able to pay with institutional loans, government-subsidized loans, and grants. This type of aid is based on financial need. Colleges also sometimes offer aid based on merit to provide an incentive for talented students to attend the institution. Financial aid is the vehicle through which colleges are able to use 1

price discrimination. Winston (1999) explains the most important characteristics of higher education and how decisions differ for a non-profit institution of higher education and a for-profit business. Universities get revenue from both students paying tuition and alumni making donations. This arrangement allows the university to subsidize their customers and charge a tuition price that is below its cost. Another unique aspect of higher education is that customers are also inputs in the other customers education. In other words, high quality students learn from each other. Rothschild and White (1995) develop an economic model for services like higher education that rely on customers as inputs. They assume that universities are profit maximizers and that they were constrained by a necessity for tuition revenue to be high enough to cover costs. Colleges compete for students through price and non-price means. Epple, Romano and Sieg (2003) assume the schools maximize their quality. The schools face a constraint where tuition and other income like endowment revenue and state subsidies must be sufficient to cover costs. In Epple, Romano and Sieg (2006), educational quality depends on ability and average income of the student body and on instructional expenditures per student. They find that low- and medium-quality colleges have limited market power and admissions decisions are mostly driven by the effective marginal cost of educating students of various abilities and incomes. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Part II introduces the model. Part III discusses the data used for estimation of the model. Part IV explains various policy experiments the model could be used to run. Part V puts forth ideas for future research. 2

Part II Model The objective of this study is to investigate how changes in pricing schemes for schools change the welfare of the school and students. Previous models of the college pricing decision like Epple, Romano and Sieg (2006) assumed the objective of the college is to maximize the quality of education it provides. In this model, college j maximizes its prestige P j, which is a function of student ability, student diversity, selectivity, and college wealth. The objective function is max p max j,f ij P j, (1) where P j = α 1 ā j + α 2 d j + α 3 s j + α 4 w j, where ā represents the mean ability of the enrolled students, d represents student diversity (the number of first-generation college attendees on campus), s represents the selectivity of the school (percentage of applicants accepted), and w represents the school s wealth. The coefficients α represent the relative weight placed on each component of prestige and will be estimated. Wealth is represented as w j = p j n j + e j, where p j represents the average price students pay for tuition, n j is the number of students enrolled, e j is other income the school receives (endowment funds, for example). Schools will choose p max j,theirmaximum( sticker )tuitionpricef ij (financial aid to student i, explained below) to maximize P j. Changes in p max j and f ij will affect p j, which in turn will affect w j in the prestige equation. In addition, price and financial aid changes will affect the types of students who are willing to attend school j, which impacts ā, d, ands. Itwouldbepossible to assume a different functional form for P j,oreventoestimatethefunctionalform,butthe linear form will be assumed here. Each school also has a budget constraint w j c j, (2) 3

where c j is the cost of running the school. There are a few notable differences in the objective function in this paper compared to the objective function in Epple, Romano and Sieg (2006). In this paper, prestige is affected by student diversity. In Epple, Romano and Sieg (2006) quality is affected by average student income. Schools place a high weight on diversity of their student body, often publishing the number of first-generation college students in their incoming classes and taking pride in admitting and helping to finance the attendance of lower-income students. The college prestige is a function of college wealth, where educational quality is a function of educational expenditures. Colleges care more about their total wealth than their educational expenditures because they can buy buildings, amenities, and more employees with their wealth. Total wealth is a more broad measure of how much money a school has than educational expenditures. Colleges are able to use tuition pricing and admissions policies to select students who will help them maximize their prestige. Students differ across four dimensions: income y i,ability a i,diversitystatusd i,andrandomtasteforaparticularcollegej, ij.income,ability,and diversity status are observable to the college. Taste for a particular college is not observed and might include factors like location or campus amenities. Student i s utility from choosing to go to school j is U ij =[y i p ij (a i,y i,d i )] + βp j + ij, (3) where p ij is the price of attending college j and P j is the utility the student gets from attending a school of prestige P. β, the utility weight of prestige, will be estimated. The weight on income net of tuition is normalized to one. The function for the price the student pays, p ij (a i,y i,d i ),isdecreasingind i,weaklydecreasinginabilityandweaklyincreasing in income. The student will choose to go to the school that presents him with the highest utility, so U i = max {U ij } j Ai, where the set A i represents the schools into which student i has gained admission. The timing of the model is as follows. First, each of the I students in the population will 4

realize his income y i,abilitya i,diversitystatusd i,andtasteforeachparticularcollegej, ij. Income, ability, and the unobserved taste are drawn independently from a distribution that for simplicity will be assumed to be normal. Diversity status, a binary variable with value one if the student is the first in his family to go to college, is one with an assumed probability p d and zero with probability 1 p d.sincethereareonlyistudents in the model and their characteristics are drawn randomly, there are a limited number of high-quality students. Schools will bid for these students by discounting the price, which will lead to different levels of prestige for different schools. Second, each school will choose a maximum price p max j and choose which students to admit. Each school will admit x jt students, where x jt is observed in the data. Each school j will rank the students based on how much prestige they will contribute to the school and accept the top x jt students. Schools will offer each student a financial aid package f ij = m ij (a i,y i,d i ), where the function m determines how much aid a student with a particular ability, income, and diversity status will receive. For simplicity in estimation, one could assume a linear functional form for m ij. The final price student i would pay at school j will be p ij (a i,y i,d i ) = min p max j,p max j f ij. Third, students will compare the utility they can receive from each school to which they were admitted, A i, and choose to go to the school which gives them the highest utility value. Schools will realize their prestige values. Part III Data The National Center for Education Statistics (NCES) collects data about educational institutions and the students who attend them. Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System (IPEDS) contains information about the institutional characteristics, prices, enroll- 5

ment, financial aid, degrees conferred, student persistence, and institutional resources. The data on tuition pricing and financial aid would be necessary for the estimation of the model specified above. IPEDS collects the average amount of financial aid received by students and the average net price for each institution. IPEDS will be used in the estimation procedure for data on average net price paid, p jt, by students at each school. IPEDS s variable that records the number of first-generation college students enrolled will be used as a proxy for d jt,studentdiversity. National Postsecondary Student Aid Survey (NPSAS) contains student-level data on financial aid. The dataset holds information about student demographic information that shapes how much colleges expect them to pay, the loans and grants colleges offer, and how much money the student pays for school. In the model outlined above, the student side of the market was simulated. Using NPSAS data instead of simulated data for students as specified above would be an option in a future study. Part IV Policy Experiments The model written above can be used to run several policy experiments. It would be interesting to see how college prestige and student utility would change if colleges were no longer able to price discriminate. If the college could not price discriminate, it would set only one price that all students would have to pay. This single price would be lower than p max above. It would be interesting to see how the prestige of each college would change and whether the total welfare for students would increase or decrease. It is likely that welfare for wealthier students would increase because they would be paying less for tuition and the welfare for poorer students would fall. A scheme with no price discrimination would likely lead to more sorting of higher-income students into the more prestigious schools. 6

Another policy experiment of interest would be to disallow price discrimination based on income only and still allow price discrimination based on ability. Such a scheme would make the price a student paid a function of ability. Schools would likely be more generous in their merit scholarships than in the base case of price discrimination based on income and ability. This would likely allow more high-ability students to go to high-prestige schools. Fewer low-ability, high-income students would choose to go to the high-prestige schools. The outcome of these policy experiments would be of interest to the government. The government currently does not interfere with the price discrimination practiced by institutions. If the above policy experiments concluded that the total welfare of students is lower under price discrimination than under a regime where all students must pay the same price, it would be evidence that the government should intervene and restrict the practice of price discrimination. Colleges argue that charging a different price for all students allows greater access to better schools for low-income students. This model would allow a researcher to check whether this argument holds true by seeing if fewer low-income students choose to go to high-prestige schools after the elimination of price discrimination. Comparing the welfare of lower-income students under different pricing schemes would be another worthwhile endeavor. An extension to the model could make feasible an policy experiment that allows colleges to choose their own pricing scheme. Perhaps some colleges would choose to charge a single price to all students, some might choose only to offer merit-based scholarships, and others could could offer both merit-based and need-based financial aid. Checking if schools of a similar prestige level choose the same pricing schemes would be interesting. Looking at how different types of students sort into schools based on their pricing behaviors could be another area of research. 7

Part V Avenues for Future Research Future researchers could add borrowing to the model. The model specified above does not allow students to take out loans to finance their education. In reality, many students rely on loans to pay for school. Allowing for borrowing would also make predictions about financial aid more reliable because the model above assumed that the entire financial aid package is composed of grants. Allowing for loans as part of financial aid would add more differentiation to financial aid offers. Another possible way to change the model would be to make it dynamic. The objective of schools would be to maximize their prestige over time. Finally, adding a time cost for applying to a school in the students utility function in order to limit the number of schools to which a student can apply would also make the model more realistic. References Epple, Dennis, Richard Romano, and Holger Sieg. 2003. Peer Effects, Financial Aid and Selection of Students into Colleges and Universities: An Empirical Analysis. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18(5):pp.501 525. Epple, Dennis, Richard Romano, and Holger Sieg. 2006. Admission, Tuition, and Financial Aid Policies in the Market for Higher Education. Econometrica, 74(4): pp. 885 928. Rothschild, Michael, and Lawrence J. White. 1995. The Analytics of the Pricing of Higher Education and Other Services in Which the Customers Are Inputs. Journal of Political Economy, 103(3):pp.573 586. 8

Winston, Gordon C. 1999. Subsidies, Hierarchy and Peers: The Awkward Economics of Higher Education. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(1): pp. 13 36. 9