Comments on Peltzman, "The Political Economy of the Decline of American Public Education"

Similar documents
CHAPTER 4: REIMBURSEMENT STRATEGIES 24

Standards, Accountability and Flexibility: Americans Speak on No Child Left Behind Reauthorization. soeak

Estimating the Cost of Meeting Student Performance Standards in the St. Louis Public Schools

Financing Education In Minnesota

THE PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIVERSITY SCHREYER HONORS COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS ASSESSING THE EFFECTIVENESS OF MULTIPLE CHOICE MATH TESTS

GDP Falls as MBA Rises?

1.0 INTRODUCTION. The purpose of the Florida school district performance review is to identify ways that a designated school district can:

November 6, Re: Higher Education Provisions in H.R. 1, the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act. Dear Chairman Brady and Ranking Member Neal:

University-Based Induction in Low-Performing Schools: Outcomes for North Carolina New Teacher Support Program Participants in

Principal vacancies and appointments

CONSISTENCY OF TRAINING AND THE LEARNING EXPERIENCE

BENCHMARK TREND COMPARISON REPORT:

University of Toronto

Arkansas Private Option Medicaid expansion is putting state taxpayers on the hook for millions in cost overruns

TUESDAYS/THURSDAYS, NOV. 11, 2014-FEB. 12, 2015 x COURSE NUMBER 6520 (1)

The Effect of Income on Educational Attainment: Evidence from State Earned Income Tax Credit Expansions

American Journal of Business Education October 2009 Volume 2, Number 7

A Study of Metacognitive Awareness of Non-English Majors in L2 Listening

Understanding and Interpreting the NRC s Data-Based Assessment of Research-Doctorate Programs in the United States (2010)

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 24 INFLATION AND THE RETURN OF OUTPUT TO POTENTIAL April 20, 2017

Evidence for Reliability, Validity and Learning Effectiveness

BASIC EDUCATION IN GHANA IN THE POST-REFORM PERIOD

University of Waterloo School of Accountancy. AFM 102: Introductory Management Accounting. Fall Term 2004: Section 4

TRENDS IN. College Pricing

NCEO Technical Report 27

The Relation Between Socioeconomic Status and Academic Achievement

Program Change Proposal:

Sector Differences in Student Learning: Differences in Achievement Gains Across School Years and During the Summer

FOUR STARS OUT OF FOUR

A Study of the Effectiveness of Using PER-Based Reforms in a Summer Setting

Edexcel GCSE. Statistics 1389 Paper 1H. June Mark Scheme. Statistics Edexcel GCSE

Honors Mathematics. Introduction and Definition of Honors Mathematics

The Internet as a Normative Corpus: Grammar Checking with a Search Engine

ABILITY SORTING AND THE IMPORTANCE OF COLLEGE QUALITY TO STUDENT ACHIEVEMENT: EVIDENCE FROM COMMUNITY COLLEGES

The Good Judgment Project: A large scale test of different methods of combining expert predictions

How and Why Has Teacher Quality Changed in Australia?

FACT: FACT: The National Coalition for Public Education. Debunking Myths About the DC Voucher Program

Pedagogical Content Knowledge for Teaching Primary Mathematics: A Case Study of Two Teachers

Proficiency Illusion

ReFresh: Retaining First Year Engineering Students and Retraining for Success

LANGUAGE DIVERSITY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT. Paul De Grauwe. University of Leuven

BEST OFFICIAL WORLD SCHOOLS DEBATE RULES

Chapter Six The Non-Monetary Benefits of Higher Education

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE UNIVERSITY OF EXETER

Rethinking the Federal Role in Elementary and Secondary Education

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WOULD THE ELIMINATION OF AFFIRMATIVE ACTION AFFECT HIGHLY QUALIFIED MINORITY APPLICANTS? EVIDENCE FROM CALIFORNIA AND TEXAS

Like much of the country, Detroit suffered significant job losses during the Great Recession.

College Pricing. Ben Johnson. April 30, Abstract. Colleges in the United States price discriminate based on student characteristics

The Relationship Between Poverty and Achievement in Maine Public Schools and a Path Forward

State Budget Update February 2016

Critical Thinking in Everyday Life: 9 Strategies

Educational Attainment

Colorado State University Department of Construction Management. Assessment Results and Action Plans

Michigan and Ohio K-12 Educational Financing Systems: Equality and Efficiency. Michael Conlin Michigan State University

Graduate Division Annual Report Key Findings

U VA THE CHANGING FACE OF UVA STUDENTS: SSESSMENT. About The Study

Robert S. Unnasch, Ph.D.

A Comparison of Charter Schools and Traditional Public Schools in Idaho

UEP 251: Economics for Planning and Policy Analysis Spring 2015

Peer Influence on Academic Achievement: Mean, Variance, and Network Effects under School Choice

How to Judge the Quality of an Objective Classroom Test

learning collegiate assessment]

About the College Board. College Board Advocacy & Policy Center

National Survey of Student Engagement

re An Interactive web based tool for sorting textbook images prior to adaptation to accessible format: Year 1 Final Report

Practices Worthy of Attention Step Up to High School Chicago Public Schools Chicago, Illinois

A non-profit educational institution dedicated to making the world a better place to live

On the Combined Behavior of Autonomous Resource Management Agents

Firms and Markets Saturdays Summer I 2014

Teacher intelligence: What is it and why do we care?

Milton Public Schools Fiscal Year 2018 Budget Presentation

Teacher Quality and Value-added Measurement

Changing User Attitudes to Reduce Spreadsheet Risk

AUTHORITATIVE SOURCES ADULT AND COMMUNITY LEARNING LEARNING PROGRAMMES

Ryerson University Sociology SOC 483: Advanced Research and Statistics

Pupil Premium Grants. Information for Parents. April 2016

IS FINANCIAL LITERACY IMPROVED BY PARTICIPATING IN A STOCK MARKET GAME?

Rote rehearsal and spacing effects in the free recall of pure and mixed lists. By: Peter P.J.L. Verkoeijen and Peter F. Delaney

Rural Education in Oregon

CLA+ Analytics: Making Data Relevant Through Data Mining in Real Time

Invest in CUNY Community Colleges

Buffalo School Board Governance


Evaluation of a College Freshman Diversity Research Program

Save Children. Can Math Recovery. before They Fail?

Managerial Decision Making

Pre-Algebra A. Syllabus. Course Overview. Course Goals. General Skills. Credit Value

The Impact of Group Contract and Governance Structure on Performance Evidence from College Classrooms

Aviation English Training: How long Does it Take?

Wisconsin 4 th Grade Reading Results on the 2015 National Assessment of Educational Progress (NAEP)

School for Graduate Studies Application Essays

Match Quality, Worker Productivity, and Worker Mobility: Direct Evidence From Teachers

1GOOD LEADERSHIP IS IMPORTANT. Principal Effectiveness and Leadership in an Era of Accountability: What Research Says

Capitalism and Higher Education: A Failed Relationship

Australia s tertiary education sector

Earnings Functions and Rates of Return

ASSESSMENT REPORT FOR GENERAL EDUCATION CATEGORY 1C: WRITING INTENSIVE

Measures of the Location of the Data

Contents. Foreword... 5

Transcription:

Santa Clara Law Santa Clara Law Digital Commons Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 1-1-1993 Comments on Peltzman, "The Political Economy of the Decline of American Public Education" David D. Friedman Santa Clara University School of Law, ddfr@daviddfriedman.com Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.scu.edu/facpubs Recommended Citation 36 J.L. & Econ. 371 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Santa Clara Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of Santa Clara Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact sculawlibrarian@gmail.com.

COMMENTS ON PELTZMAN, "THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE DECLINE OF AMERICAN PUBLIC EDUCATION"* DAVID D. FRIEDMAN University of Chicago I. A PROBLEM PELTZMAN uses interstate data to explain changes in school performance, concentrating on variables that affect the political system controlling the schools. There is a serious risk that such a procedure may produce false positives. It is well established that the family background of students is a major determinant, perhaps the major determinant, of performance. Variables describing family background by state are likely to correlate with other state variables, including the sort Peltzman is interested in. Results that appear to show the influence of unionization, or centralization of school financing, or the needs of employers may merely mean that those variables are serving as proxies for environmental variables. This is a familiar problem in statistics, and one for which multiple regressions are a common solution, but it is particularly serious here for two reasons. The first is that there is some reason to suspect that environmental variables may be much more powerful determinants of the dependent variable than political variables. The second is that it is unclear what environmental variables at what dates should be controlled for. A graduating senior has spent twelve years in the school system and eighteen in his family. If, as some would argue, it is early childhood development that determines later performance, the relevant environmental variables may enter with lags of well over a decade. Peltzman attempted to control for environmental effects by adding several environmental vari- * Presented at the John M. Olin Centennial Conference in Law and Economics at the University of Chicago Law School, Chicago, April 7-9, 1992. [Journal of Law & Economics, vol. XXXVI (April 1993)] 1993 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-2186/93/3601-0015$01.50 HeinOnline -- 36 J.L. & Econ. 371 1993

THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS TABLE I CORRELATION COEFFICIENTS OF SOME ADDITIONAL VARIABLES SCHOOL PERFORMANCE 1972-81 1981-89 DBRK FAM80 FAM60 INC70/60 CONS 1. DBRK.141 -.225 1.000 2. FAM80 -.546 -. 144 -.445 1.000 3. FAM60 -. 508 -. 307.171.806 1.000 4. Inc70/60.359.282 -.441 -.404 -.736 1.000 5. Cons.311.314 -.367 -.295 -.567.513 1.000 6. pnea.114 -.263.444.142.450 -.462 -.467 7. paft -. 193 -.260.544 -.082.269 -.209 -.522 NoTE.-See text for definition of variables. ables to his regressions and found that they did not have much effect on the results, but that may mean only that he did not try the right ones. In order to explore this possibility, I experimented with a number of additional variables. Table 1 shows part of a correlation matrix relating Peltzman's measure of performance growth, his union variables, and a number of variables relevant to student backgrounds.' The most striking result appears on lines 2 and 3. The variables FAM80 and FAM60 show the percentage of children under age eighteen from broken homes in 1980 and 1960, respectively. Either variable, by itself, fits changes in school performance from 1972 to 1981 with a correlation coefficient greater than.5. The variable DBRK, the change in the percentage of children from broken homes from 1960 to 1980, correlates much more weakly with school performance-and with the wrong sign. We would expect broken families to result in worse educational outcomes, but why is it the level rather than the change that is significant? One possible explanation is long time lags; the level in 1960 may be a proxy for changes prior to that date whose effect shows itself in students graduating in the seventies. A second answer is that we may be observing the combined effect of a family variable and a change in the schools. Charles Murray, in Losing Ground, 2 argues that one of the problems with the educational system during the sixties and seventies was a shift of attention from the best to the worst students. If so, we might expect states where there were a lot of problem students, because of a high t The variables FAM60, FAM80, pnea, and paft and the school performance variables are from Peltzman's data, to which he kindly permitted me access. 2 Charles Murray, Losing Ground: American Social Policy, 1950-1980 (1984). HeinOnline -- 36 J.L. & Econ. 372 1993

COMMENT I TABLE 2 RELATIVE TEST SCORE CHANGES: STATES, 1972-81 R 2 = 56.6% R 2 (adjusted) = 49.5% s = 1.160 with 44-7 = 37 degrees of freedom Variable Coefficient t-ratio Constant 4.15424.754 "Real" expenditure per pupil, 1961-81 2.60635 1.25 pnea 2.77758 3.46 paft -5.03255-2.99 FAM80-14.1430-2.89 RIn70/60 3.36275 1.62 Enrollment per district 78/57 -. 110184-1.61 NOTE.-See text for definition of variables. level of broken families, to have a particular sharp decline in educational performance over that period. In addition to FAM80 and FAM60, other variables that correlate more strongly with school performance from 1972 to 1981 than do Peltzman's union variables are Inc70/60 (the percentage growth in real per capita income from 1960 to 1970) and Cons (the sum of the Republican vote percentages in the presidential elections of 1964 and 1972). In order to see whether these variables might explain away Peltzman's results, I reran several of his regressions, including various selections of these additional variables. Table 2 shows the result of one such regression, corresponding to Peltzman's table 5, regression 3, with a few changes. The main effect of the added variables was to sizably increase K2 from.29 in regression 3 on Peltzman's table 5 to.495 for the regression shown in Table 2 above. 3 Although adding additional variables weakened the significance of some existing variables and increased that of others, the general pattern remained the same, suggesting that Peltzman's results are reasonably robust-although there is always the possibility that they would be eliminated by the inclusion of some other environmental variable that neither he nor I have tried. An alternative approach to avoiding confusion between the effects of political and environmental variables would be to find political variables 3 The dependent variable, as in Peltzman's table 5, is the coefficient of regression of average test scores on time, 1972-81. Enrollment per district 78/57 is my measure of changes in enrollment per school district, discussed infra. Its inclusion tends to weaken or eliminate the significance of the change in the state government share of public school expenditure, as one might expect, since they are both measures of the shift toward centralization. Similarly, the inclusion of Cons, my measure of how conservative a state is politically, tends to weaken the significance of Peltzman's Teacher's Bargaining Rights Law Index (1972). HeinOnline -- 36 J.L. & Econ. 373 1993

THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS that we have good reason to believe are independent of environmental variables-ideally, political outcomes that are the result of random causes. I have one suggestion along those lines. We would expect electoral results to correlate in a continuous fashion with population characteristics such as income, education, or family structure; as certain characteristics become more common, vote totals for one party or ideology should change accordingly. Political outcomes, however, depend on electoral outcomes in a highly discontinuous fashion. While any change in a party's vote total affects its political strength, the increase from 49.9 percent to 50.1 percent has a much larger effect than an increase from 50.1 percent to 50.3 percent. This suggests that one could distinguish the political outcome from the electoral outcome in a regression by including one variable for percentage of votes by one party and a second showing the number of years during which that party held the governorship. The first variable should pick up effects associated with nonpolitical variables that correlate with voting patterns, making the second a reasonably good measure of the consequences of different political outcomes. II. AN ALTERNATIVE POLITICAL EXPLANATION Peltzman discusses a variety of possible causes for the decline in American schooling, but his fundamental model is one in which the change is due to a change in the power or objectives of the interest groups influencing the political institutions that control the schools. While I agree with the underlying idea of looking for an explanation based on the behavior of those institutions, I would like to suggest a slightly different approach-one based not on changes in the interest groups but on changes in the level of government at which the decision is made. Such changes are important for at least three different reasons. One is that different levels of government may be subject to different interest groups with different interests. A firm that is the main employer in a small town is a highly concentrated interest with regard to the school board of that town, but part of a rather dispersed interest with regard to the state legislature and a still more dispersed interest with regard to Congress, so its influence will be much greater if local school districts are small and independent. 4 A second reason why the level of government matters is that the relevance of the interest group model may depend on the level of government. In a naive model of democracy, elected politicians do good things 4 This point is made in Peltzman's article, although it is not central to his argument. HeinOnline -- 36 J.L. & Econ. 374 1993

COMMENT I because that is what the voters who elect them want. This is a poor description of the working of large governments because of rational ignorance; it is rarely worth the cost to an individual voter to discover whether his elected politicians are acting in his interest and to do something about it. The result is a political system dominated by concentrated interest groups. But the naive model may work fairly well for a small town school board, where parent voters get information about the school's performance five days a week, at no cost, and where the number of voters is small enough so that individuals or small groups may hope to have some influence. If, as seems likely, the individual voter cares more about the educational quality of the school his children go to than the average of the interest groups affecting the schools, this effect will tend to produce a positive correlation between local control of schooling and schooling quality. A third reason size matters is that it affects the degree to which governments compete with each other for taxpayers. In a system where schools are locally run and funded from local taxes, the resources available to the local government depend to a substantial degree on how good the schools are, since many taxpayers decide where to live in part on the basis of school quality. That provides the local government and the local school administration with a direct interest in educational quality, quite aside from political activity by parents or other groups interested in good schools. This third effect depends on both local control and local funding. If schools are funded entirely from state taxes, local control may reduce the problem of rational ignorance among the voters, but it will not give local school districts any incentive to use educational quality to attract taxpayers. All three of these arguments suggest that a movement away from local control and funding of education might well result in a decline in educational quality. This seems consistent with our experience. From 1946 to 1974, the number of school districts in the United States fell about sixfold and the number of students roughly doubled, producing an increase of more than an order of magnitude in the number of students per school district. Since 1974 the number of students per school district has been roughly constant. That pattern fits reasonably well the pattern of educational outcomes over time. In addition, as Peltzman points out, there was a substantial shift from local to state funding of schooling over the period when school performance was declining. To test the possibility that the increasing size of school districts was in part responsible for the decline in educational achievement, I ran a number of regressions using changes in number of school districts or enrollment per district to fit changes in educational achievement. Using HeinOnline -- 36 J.L. & Econ. 375 1993

THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS the ratio of enrollment per districts in 1978 to enrollment per district in 1957 to fit the change in achievement from 1972 to 1981 gave an R2 of.181 percent and a t equal to -3.24. The effect was reduced substantially (t = - 1.67) if I included in the regression a measure of children from broken homes in 1980-which, as discussed earlier, correlates quite highly with school performance in the following two decades. The effect of this measure of changing school district size on changes in achievement from 1981 to 1989 was not significant. Adding this variable to regression 3 reported in Peltzman's table 5 reduced the significance of his measure of school centralization (the roll of state funding), as would be expected, but did not eliminate the significance of his other variables. These results may well underestimate the importance of increasing size of districts, due to a problem with the data. It is easy to calculate the ratio of enrollment to number of school districts in a state, which is what I did. But this gives an average over districts, not over students; it tells us how many students the average district has but not how large a district the average student is in. A state with one district containing a million students and one containing a thousand appears, by this measure, to have an average of 500,500 students per district. But in such a state, 99.9 percent of the students are in a million-student district; district size averaged over students is 999,002 students per district. How serious, in practice, is the distortion that results from averaging over districts rather than over students? For the state of California for 1977-78, I was able to obtain enough information on individual districts to calculate an approximate answer to that question. Averaged over districts, the figure was about four thousand students per district. Averaged over students it was over eighty thousand. If such differences are typical, and if they vary significantly from state to state, they introduce a large element of noise into my regression. This suggests that it would be worth trying to calculate, for each state, the figure averaged over students and seeing whether that statistic predicts school performance even better than the statistic I measured. III. MISPLACED SKEPTICISM The following summarizes an argument Peltzman makes for skepticism with regard to the evidence that "resources do not matter." If the marginal return of expenditure on educational achievement is independent of the student's background, and if the utility function being maximized by the government has declining marginal utility of student achievement, the government will tend to allocate more money to students with worse backgrounds, although not enough more to bring their HeinOnline -- 36 J.L. & Econ. 376 1993

COMMENT I achievement up to the level of those with better backgrounds. Unmeasured background characteristics will then correlate positively with achievement and negatively with expenditure, creating the illusion of a negative correlation between expenditure and achievement. The fictitious negative correlation may cancel out a real positive correlation, making it look as though expenditure has no effect on achievement. The problem with this argument is that it proves too much. If we substitute the employer's utility function for the government's, it implies that employers typically invest more money training their less able employees. If we substitute the parent's utility function, it implies that poor but aspiring parents scrimp to provide additional education to their least able children. If we substitute the utility function of the political structure controlling state higher education, it implies that the state universities admit from the bottom instead of the top of the distribution of graduating seniors and specialize in remedial rather than advanced education. Casual observation suggests, in each case, the opposite pattern. That implies either that the marginal return is higher for expenditures on abler students or that utility functions for educational achievement exhibit increasing marginal utility in the relevant range. If this conclusion is correct, the argument Peltzman offers works in reverse. Expenditures will tend to be higher, not lower, on students with better backgrounds. Unobserved variation in background will correlate positively with both expenditure and achievement, creating the illusion of a positive correlation between expenditure and achievement. The measured correlation will then overstate the actual correlation. If, as Peltzman reports, the observed correlation is negligible, this argument strengthens the conclusion that resources do not matter-or converts it to the even stronger conclusion that increases in resources reduce achievement. IV. MARGINAL EMPLOYERS Peltzman finds that an increase in the skill level of employees of industries concentrated in a state correlates negatively with changes in educational quality. I find this result less surprising than he does, for two reasons. One of them he discusses. A local industry that hires workers directly out of high school will be more interested in the quality of local education than one that hires college graduates since a larger fraction of its employees will be graduates of the local school system. The second reason is more complicated. During the sixties and seventies, the percentage of college-educated workers was rising, but the fraction of the population going to college was roughly constant. The explana- HeinOnline -- 36 J.L. & Econ. 377 1993

THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS tion of this apparent paradox is that the fraction of the population graduating from college was much higher in this period than in preceding decades. The effects Peltzman is looking for depend on changes in the skill level of new hires, but the variable he constructs measures changes in the skill level of the entire work force. A firm for which college graduates made up 8 percent of the work force at the beginning of the period but 25 percent of new hires (roughly the average figures for the adult population at the time) would report a steadily rising skill level, even if the skill level of new hires remained unchanged throughout the period. So industries that Peltzman interprets as having a rising share of college-educated hires may simply be ones that started the period with a work force that contained few college graduates and had a larger but constant fraction of college graduates as new hires during the period. Such industries would have been a political force in favor of good local schools at the beginning of the period. By the end of the period the shift away from local control of education would have substantially reduced their influence, quite aside from any change in the composition of the industry's work force or new hires. This provides a second possible explanation for the negative correlation between skill level of industry and quality of schooling. V. CONCLUSION This article makes a good start on the project of using interstate variation to explain the change in school performance on the basis of changes affecting the political institutions that control American schools and produces some suggestive results. The main improvements I would suggest are a greater effort to find and control for the relevant nonpolitical variables, and a more careful examination of the possibility that the drastic centralization of control and financing of the schools during the postwar period may have been one of the crucial political changes responsible for the decline in school performance. HeinOnline -- 36 J.L. & Econ. 378 1993